Cross-posted at Reports From the Economic Front.
The media generally talk about the economy in national terms — as if economic trends affect us all equally and we all share a common interest in supporting or opposing the same economic policies. This comforting view tends to promote political passivity — since we are all in the same “boat,” it makes sense to leave policy making to the experts.
A recently published study on income distribution by economists Anthony Atkinson, Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez stands as a welcome corrective. Uwe E. Reinhardt discusses some of the main implications of their work in his New York Times blog.
Reinhardt’s Figure 1 shows average annual income growth for households in the United States and the different experiences of the top 1% and the bottom 99%. From 1976 to 2007, average household income grew at an average annual rate of 1.2%. Over the same period, the top 1% of households experienced an average annual income gain of 4.4% while the bottom 99% of households gained only 0.6% a year. Household income gains were higher in both subperiods (1993-2000 and 2002-2007), in large part because these subperiods were recession free.
Figure 2 shows the share of total income growth in each time period that was captured by the top 1% of households. Over the years 1976 to 2007, these households captured 58% of all income generated. Their share was an astounding 65% in the period 2002 to 2007.
This skewed income distribution means that average income figures present a highly misleading picture of the American experience. As Reinhardt explains:
So if an American macroeconomist — a specialist who tends to think of nations as people — or high-level government officials or politicians mimicking a macroeconomist boasted on a television talk show that “average family income grew by 3 percent during 2002-7, more than in most European economies,” about 99 percent of American viewers, reflecting on their own experience, would probably scratch their heads and wonder, “What is this guy talking about?”
Figure 3 highlights the growth in real GDP per capita and median household income from 1975 to 2007. The data show a growing divergence between what working people produced and what the average household received from that production. Real GDP per capita rose by an annual compound rate of 1.9% while real median household income increased by less than 0.5%.
As Reinhardt points out: “Other than national pride in league tables, that 1.9 percent average economic growth does not mean much for the experience of the median household in the United States.”
This brings us back to the issue of whether it makes sense to talk in “national” terms, especially given the dominance of the top 1% of households. According to Anthony Atkinson, Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez:
Average real income per family in the United States grew by 32.2 percent from 1975 to 2006, while they grew only by 27.1 percent in France during the same period, showing that the macroeconomic performance in the United States was better than the French one during this period. Excluding the top percentile, average United States real incomes grew by only 17.9 percent during the period while average French real incomes — excluding the top percentile — still grew at much the same rate (26.4 percent) as for the whole French population. Therefore, the better macroeconomic performance of the United States and France is reversed when excluding the top 1 percent.
None of this is to suggest that U.S. society is best understood in terms of a simple division between the top 1% and the bottom 99%; the latter group is far from homogeneous. Still, this division alone is big enough to establish that talking in simple national terms hides more than it illuminates about the American experience. Said differently, just because the top 1% of U.S. households have reason to celebrate the U.S. economic model doesn’t mean that the rest of us should join in the celebration.
Comments 5
Yrro Simyarin — September 6, 2011
Of course, the comparison to France completely leaves out the fact that they were starting from a *much* lower level of production. It has been shown that countries with lower per capita GDP's have a much easier time of producing higher growth rates and more distributed growth, as there are more lower hanging fruit and obvious inefficiencies.
Even today, if France were a state, it would be the one of the poorest five.
Things like this make direct cross-country comparisons fairly tricky. Even within a country... I'm curious how this growth looks regionally. Are only California and New York getting rich, or are the top educated earners across the country seeing this level of growth?
Jeff Cuscutis — September 6, 2011
Why do the first two graphs overlap their ranges?
1976-2007
1993-2000
2002-2007
How are we supposed to really see the difference over time?
It has the appearance at least of cherry picking data.
Chris J. Rodgers — September 7, 2011
One thing is for sure, fig. 3 definitely shows that even though we, as a country are producing much more, we who are doing the work aren't benefiting from the fruits of our labor.
5 Ways to Avoid Diabetes; The Benefits of Exercise Add-Up; And More « Welcome to the Doctor's Office — September 7, 2011
[...] ONE NATION DIVISIBLE by Martin Hart-Landsberg [...]